Thursday, April 23, 2009

Liquidity and banks – a primer


Several of the responses to the last post (about bank excess liquidity) seemed to confuse liquidity and solvency.  Indeed several confused “cash reserves” with “loan loss reserves” and the like.

Aaron Krowne – a fairly sophisticated guy and the proprietor of the Mortgage Implode-O-Meter for instance suggested that the 170 billion in cash is necessary to meet loan losses.

Let’s get this right.  A bank’s liquidity goes down when they lend money.  They lend their liquidity.

A bank’s liquidity does not go down when there are loan losses.  You do not need cash to deal with loan losses.  You need net worth to deal with loan losses.

A bank really needs liquidity to deal with people being unwilling to leave their funds either on deposit to a bank or on loan to a bank.  If a bank gets a run on deposits (even a small run) it needs liquidity and it needs it bad.  This is essentially unpredictable.  If it cannot roll its own funding it needs liquidity and it needs it bad however this is more predictable because there will be a known debt maturity schedule they need to meet.

Bank of America carries 170 billion in cash rather than the more normal 30-40 billion because it is scared of runs (both retail and wholesale).

The wholesale run is happening and has been happening ever since that fateful week in September when bank creditors realised that – on the say-so of Sheila Bair – they could lose their assets entirely.  [Washington Mutual as originally confiscated left the senior debt holders essentially nothing.]

Still fear – and fear alone – can run a big bank out of liquidity.  You do not need to be insolvent as a bank to become illiquid.  Pretty well the entire Norwegian banking system was illiquid and confiscated during the 1992 Norwegian banking crisis.  Capital was constrained but the government made a profit on the bank-bail-out suggesting (ex-poste) that the problem was a liquidity crisis and not a solvency crisis.  [Unfortunately nobody, government or private sector, knew for certain whether the issue was solvency or liquidity during 1992 though plenty of people expressed very strong opinions many of which were wrong.]

But get this – and remember it well.  In traditional banking cash held by the bank beyond simple transactional balances exists solely to deal with fear.  If there is no fear then banks have no liquidity problem.  And they will have no liquidity problem even if they are staggeringly insolvent.  Indeed many Japanese banks had no fear, staggering insolvency and operated for more than a decade.  Closer to home Conseco Finance was almost certainly insolvent a few years before it collapsed.

I got at least a dozen emails that thought that liquidity at Bank of America was to do with losses.  All of them misunderstood this simple and key point.  

Now investment bank liquidity is much more complicated.  The most controversial example is credit default swaps – especially margined credit default swaps.

Writing a credit default swap is in many respects very similar to making a loan.  The credit risk – the key risk – is almost identical.

But when you make loans cash walks out the door immediately.  You have to have cash to make loans.  If you have only limited cash then you cannot make unlimited loans and so you will tend to be selective about the loans you make (choosing better credits).  If you have to raise cash in order to finance lending then you need to go to market (issue bonds etc) and that imposes some discipline and costs on you.

When you write a credit default swap you just need someone to have faith that you are good for the exposure.

No cash walks out the door.  

Lending imposes the discipline of being required to have cash.  Writing CDS does not.

Felix Salmon (and others) have had long arguments about whether CDS caused or exacerbated the crisis.  In most this argument I agree with Felix, but the ability to write vast amounts of CDS without needing cash was important in some parts of the crisis.  Plain old lending has more discipline.  This was certainly a large part of the problem at AIG, MBIA and Ambac.  

But CDS have another property.  CDS (unlike loans) do not require cash when they are written.  But CDS (also unlike loans) cause a cash drain when they default.

A bank which writes CDS needs cash to deal with credit losses.  A bank which does traditional lending does not.

Unfortunately CDS cash requirements go up in a financial crisis.  That is when the cash gets called.  

And that is also precisely the time when banks have most fear surrounding them and hence most difficulty raising cash.  CDS give financial institutions a cash call at precisely the wrong time.  That is why – if anything – they exacerbated the crisis.  

Lines of credit written by banks (Citigroup and JP Morgan were huge writers) also require cash precisely in times of crisis.  Most the time you write the line of credit and there is no cash drain on the bank.  But when the customer is stressed the lines of credit will be drawn.  That also – by usual correlation – tends to be the time that bank liquidity is most difficult.

Still – and this is my reaction from picking apart Bank of America – most of the huge cash balance of bank of America is to deal with fear in the funding markets – and very little is required to deal with loan losses.

Capital – that is net assets – is what is required to deal with loan losses.  Cash on hand is frankly irrelevant for that.  Whether Bank of America has sufficient net assets to deal with their (large) loan losses is a matter of widespread disputes.  Many strong and differing opinions exist – and inevitably some of them will be wrong.

11 comments:

MDZ said...

OTC derivative collateral requirements are a function of the pricing of the contract and the rating of the entity -- so you can get a run on a "bank" from a rating change or from an adverse change in interest rates, if like BofA, they use interest rate derivatives extensively.

The OTC collateral balances were at $4 trillion as of the end of the year per ISDA, up $1.9 trillion during 2008. These collateral calls on bad contracts are still the whammy that has to have the big banks concerned.

Amazing that this hasn't really been discussed anywhere. Bloomberg refers to "soul-searching" today, but not the $1.9 trillion...

Anonymous said...

Thanks for giving some clarity. They don't teach us this stuff as an undergrad :)

IF said...

Was Madoff just a liquid but insolvent bank? At which point does a liquid but insolvent bank become a Ponzi scheme? And finally, which is the minimum amount of document forging that will sent such a bank CFO to jail? Questions, questions.

Anonymous said...

"But CDS (also unlike loans) cause a cash drain when they default"

Not just on default. A major problem is the cash drain to deal with Mr Markets increased perception of default risk in the form of collateral posting. This caused a feedback loop.

John Hempton said...

I did say that especially collateralised CDS were difficult.

J

MW said...

"...the ability to write vast amounts of CDS without needing cash was important in some parts of the crisis."

This is NOT a problem with CDS --- it's a problem with counterparty risk management, in that firms got away with not posting collateral. That would never happen with options, FX, futures, blah...

the big dumb said...

solvency/liquidity tutorials to undergrads are fine, but GE is up 100% since you made the no buy call, mr hempton.

how much is that annualized and how do you like your crow?

Mugpunter said...

The opening ended selling of risk is the problem in the CDS market, not the CDS itself.

If large institutions had to post the same collateral as all market particpants (such as hedge funds) when they enetered into these contracts we wouldn't see the liquidity mismatch you're talking about.

The ability to sell CDS portection without posting collateral allowed AIG and other institutions (*cough* Berkshire *cough*) to generate infinite IRR on the assumption there was no risk of default.

Force all particpants to post homogenous levels of collateral like the equity options market does and it will remove the problem. This is no surprise really, because the CDS market is in many ways simply a bond option market.

gaius marius said...

jh, is it not possible that BAC is holding cash not in fear of runs (though useful if one comes) but in anticipation of further collateral postings -- not only on CDS but on interest rate swaps -- as credit deteriorates?

o. nate said...

Is the banks' strong liquidity preference a reasonable one, considering that they are currently relying to a large extent on FDIC guarantees of their debt and an implicit "No More Lehmans" pledge to motivate investors to hold their debt? If bank debtholders started facing haircuts or forced equity conversions, as some observers are advocating, wouldn't the banks' cost of funding go through the roof? In that case, the more cash on hand, the better.

babar ganesh said...

note that Mish is making the same mistake in this: http://globaleconomicanalysis.blogspot.com/2009/04/money-multipliers-velocity-and-excess.html

quote: "Excess reserves are rising ... because banks are preparing in advance for future writeoffs, not because the increased demand for money means there is less money to lend."

General disclaimer

The content contained in this blog represents the opinions of Mr. Hempton. You should assume Mr. Hempton and his affiliates have positions in the securities discussed in this blog, and such beneficial ownership can create a conflict of interest regarding the objectivity of this blog. Statements in the blog are not guarantees of future performance and are subject to certain risks, uncertainties and other factors. Certain information in this blog concerning economic trends and performance is based on or derived from information provided by third-party sources. Mr. Hempton does not guarantee the accuracy of such information and has not independently verified the accuracy or completeness of such information or the assumptions on which such information is based. Such information may change after it is posted and Mr. Hempton is not obligated to, and may not, update it. The commentary in this blog in no way constitutes a solicitation of business, an offer of a security or a solicitation to purchase a security, or investment advice. In fact, it should not be relied upon in making investment decisions, ever. It is intended solely for the entertainment of the reader, and the author. In particular this blog is not directed for investment purposes at US Persons.